News Story

U.S. Supreme Court Accepts Case to Give 'Right-to-Work' to All Public Employees

Court could end compulsory union 'agency fee' payments for government workers

On the final day of its most recent session, the U.S. Supreme Court announced it will consider a labor law case that experts say could dramatically limit the power of government employee unions.

Friedrichs v. California Teachers Association was brought on behalf of 10 California public school teachers who sued for the right to leave their union and not still pay "agency fees." If the Supreme Court rules in their favor, it could have the same effect as extending right-to-work law protections to all public employees by invalidating the involuntary extraction of agency fees from worker paychecks. Previous decisions have recognized workers' right to not have union dues extracted, but agency fees are still allowed. These fees are typically 80 percent of the full dues payments.

Michigan's Mackinac Center Legal Foundation is among the organizations that filed an amicus brief in favor of the teachers.

“The significance of Friedrichs cannot be understated,” said F. Vincent Vernuccio, the director of labor policy at the Mackinac Center for Public Policy. “If the Supreme Court sides with the California teachers it could mean right-to-work for public employees across the country, protected by the First Amendment. Government unions in the remaining 25 states which allow unions to get workers fired for not paying them could no longer force public employees to support an organization they disagree with.”

Unions argue that without compulsory dues or fees, many workers will enjoy the benefits of union representation without paying for it. This is among complaints made by the Michigan Education Association against the right-to-work law enacted in Michigan in 2012. Union officials have used the term “freeloaders” to describe employees who stop paying dues or fees under right-to-work but don't want to be excluded from being covered under MEA contracts.

In 2013, Sen. Arlan Meekhof, R-West Olive, asked MEA spokesman Doug Pratt about this.

"Sometimes I've heard of people who want to leave the union [described as] as 'freeloader'," Meekhof said. "Is there contention by the MEA that you would wish to be relieved of representing those people who want to opt out of the union?"

Pratt answered, "No."

Lee Adler, who teaches public sector collective bargaining and labor law at Cornell University, pointed to the Supreme Court’s Harris vs. Quinn ruling in 2014. The Court ruled in a 5-4 decision that it was a violation of the First Amendment to allow unions to deduct fees from nonunion members.

“It is not often that the Court so quickly revisits an issue such as deduction of union dues from a worker’s pay, but they have done so here,” Adler said in an email. “It may mean that they wish to extend the Harris ruling which allowed workers to not pay partial union dues, or agency fee dues, to full-fledged teacher-employees. Such a ruling would financially harm public sector unions, America’s strongest unions. It would also be contrary to observations about the history of labor law in the U.S. made at oral argument by Justice Scalia and run counter to a decades-long consensus (and precedents) on the national balance crafted by the Court which shapes labor relations and dues paying in both sectors for employees and their unions.”

“Given the reasoning in Justice Alito’s Harris ruling and the Court’s own long-standing precedents, it will be very difficult for Justice Alito to get the five votes necessary for the Court to extend its view that dues paying by full-fledged union members (as opposed to the ‘provisional,' nonstate employees covered by the Harris decision) is constitutionally coercive and thus invalid.”

Michigan Capitol Confidential is the news source produced by the Mackinac Center for Public Policy. Michigan Capitol Confidential reports with a free-market news perspective.

Commentary

Michigan House Wise to Shift Corporate Welfare Spending to Roads

Programs shown to be ineffective and wasteful

The state House of Representatives recently cut funding for the Michigan Economic Development Corporation with the goal of freeing up money for roads. This reprioritization of spending is prudent, but it faces opposition in the state Senate.

A good deal of empirical evidence supports the case that government economic development policies — otherwise known as corporate welfare — are ineffective at achieving their goals of faster economic growth, increased employment and greater diversification.

For example, a 2004 study titled, “The Failure of Economic Development Incentives” was a review and analysis of the academic literature on the subject of MEDC-type programs. The authors categorized and reviewed hundreds of other academic studies on the subject. Their conclusion is worth repeating:

The most fundamental problem is that many public officials appear to believe that they can influence the course of their state and local economies through incentives and subsidies to a degree far beyond anything supported by even the most optimistic evidence. We need to begin by lowering [policymakers'] expectations about their ability to micromanage economic growth and making the case for a more sensible view of the role of government. …

A few years back one of the study’s authors (Peter Fisher) was asked by The Detroit News whether eliminating the Michigan Economic Growth Authority, then the state’s flagship business subsidy program, would amount to “unilateral disarmament” given that other states have similar programs. “Of course you can unilaterally disarm when you’re talking about an incentive — like the MEGA tax credit — that isn’t very effective anyway,” he said.

Before it was repealed in 2011, MEGA was arguably the most costly economic development program in this state’s history. Over the past decade the program was the subject of four methodologically rigorous studies. The empirical evidence on its performance is not, on balance, positive. It suggests the smaller subsidy programs that remain are unlikely to do better.

Two of these studies were performed by the Mackinac Center for Public Policy. One of these found in 2005 that for every $123,000 in tax credits offered by the program, just one construction job was created — and that all of the jobs created by the credits disappeared within two years. The other study, published in 2009, found that for every $1 million in tax credits delivered to a project there was a decrease of 95 manufacturing jobs in the county where it was located.

In 2010 the Anderson Economic Group ran the numbers on MEGA. It found that had Lansing cut business taxes across-the-board rather than doling out MEGA favors to a lucky few firms, Michigan businesses would have created 8,200 more jobs.

Only one of the four studies purported to show a positive impact from MEGA, and even then the impact was very small. It was authored by economists at the W. E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, and disagreed with the Mackinac Center’s interpretation of the data on MEGA. You can read the Mackinac Center’s rejoinder here.

If MEGA’s massive subsidies and selective tax breaks were ineffective, there is little basis to expect different outcomes from its small-fry brethren. One of these is the indirect tourism subsidies offered through the state’s “Pure Michigan” ads.

The title of a Mackinac Center analysis on the subject (2015) tells the tale: State Tourism Spending Ineffective. The study’s authors developed a statistical model using tourism promotion spending in 48 states to measure the impact that such subsidies have on tourism businesses and employment. The model reported that every $1.00 increase in state dollars promoting tourism yields around one penny of extra business for firms in Michigan’s lodging industry. When the net costs are considered, the program actually does more economic harm than good.

Another study worth mentioning was performed in 2002 by economist Harold Brumm on selective favor-seeking activity by businesses (called “rent-seeking” by economists). Brumm examined data from the lower 48 states and found that “Rent-seeking activity retards economic growth, because it merely redistributes wealth; rent seekers (unlike profit seekers in a competitive market) do not create wealth.” He concluded that the more rent-seeking occurs, the slower the rate of real economic growth.

One conclusion from Brumm’s findings is that when a state department like the MEDC encourages corporate rent-seeking, it may actually limit a state’s growth prospects.

Given all these findings, the Michigan House made a prudent and rational choice in moving state tax dollars out of corporate welfare and into road repairs. The Senate should do the same. If senators hesitate then the burden of proof should be on them to produce systematic evidence —not fluffy agency brochures and anecdotes —­ that corporate welfare programs are a more effective use of taxpayer dollars than road repairs.

Michigan Capitol Confidential is the news source produced by the Mackinac Center for Public Policy. Michigan Capitol Confidential reports with a free-market news perspective.